Etikk i praksis. Nordic Journal of Applied Ethics (2016),
10 (1), 45–59
http://dx.doi.org/10.5324/eip.v10i1.1969
Public domain as a
master frame?
Sebastian
Haunss
University of Bremen, SOCIUM – Research Center on
Inequality and Social Policy,
sebastian.haunss@uni-bremen.de
In a widely cited article Boyle suggests that a
movement against the growing propertization of knowledge
should develop a mobilization frame centered around the
idea of the public domain. Based on an analysis of the
framing strategies in the two most important protest
mobilizations against extensive intellectual property
rights I discuss whether and to which degree these
movements did actually put the concept of the public
domain at the center of their argumentation. The article
uses political claims analysis and discourse analysis to
show that the actual framing strategies relied on other
frames. It closes with a discussion, explaining why the
idea of the public domain is essentially a defensive
concept with a limited potential for movements that
primarily address the production of knowledge.
Keywords: Intellectual Property Rights, Public
Domain, Social Movements, Knowledge Society, Discourse
Analysis
In a widely cited article, James Boyle
(2003) develops a powerful narrative of intellectual
property rights as the “second enclosure movement”.
While the first enclosure movement transformed public
land into private property, the second enclosure
movement transforms “the intangible commons of the mind”
(Boyle 2003: 37) into intellectual property. In both
cases, public access is restricted by creating exclusive
rights. To counter the growing propertization of
knowledge, Boyle argues that the idea of the public
domain has to be developed. Like the notion of “the
environment” that had to be developed before it was
possible to bring together nature enthusiasts,
conservationists, ecologists and others in the
environmental movement, “an emergent concept of the
public domain could tie together the interests of groups
currently engaged in individual struggles with no sense
of the larger context” (Boyle 2003: 71) in the field of
the politics of intellectual property (Haunss &
Shadlen 2009). Boyle thus suggests that a movement
against the growing propertization of knowledge should
develop a mobilization frame centered on the idea of the
public domain.
More than a decade after this proposal was made, we can
indeed see a revival of the ideas of the public domain
and the commons. In the digital realm, Creative Commons
has proven to be a veritable success story. Since
December 2002, when the first Creative Commons license
was issued, millions of Internet users have chosen to
release their creative works (text, pictures, music,
etc.) under a license that largely reverses the
exclusiveness and restrictions of traditional copyrights
(Dusollier 2006). The most recent data available shows
that since then, not only the absolute number of
licenses but also the license adoption rate is still
growing, so that Creative Commons was able to announce
at the end of 2015 that over 1 billion works have been
made available under its licenses (Creative Commons
2015). And in addition to individual Internet users,
governments, public administrations and scientific
organizations are also releasing their data and works
under a Creative Commons license. The success of the
idea of a digital commons is paralleled by a growing
interest for the idea of the commons in the analog world
as well – especially after Elinor Ostrom received the in
2009 the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences for
her institutional economic studies on the governance of
the commons (Ostrom 1990).
Has the concept of the public domain or the commons in
effect become a unifying master frame (Snow &
Benford 1992: 138), bringing together various
organizations and protests under a shared interpretation
and with a common goal? Have these concepts played a
central role in recent conflicts about intellectual
property rights? Or do other frames play a more central
role in uniting social movements that are addressing
conflicts of the knowledge society?
To answer these questions, I will analyze the framing
strategies of the opponents of strong intellectual
property rights by focusing on two conflicts in the
field of the politics of intellectual property: 1) the
global mobilization on access to medicines, and 2) the
European conflict over software patents. These two
conflicts so far represent the largest mobilizations in
which intellectual property rights have been politicized
and which involved forms of action usually associated
with social movements – most importantly large-scale
public protests. Moreover, each conflict has developed a
lasting impact on IP politics. For both cases, the
analysis will examine whether and to what degree frames
about the public domain and the commons functioned as a
master frame uniting various actors’ argumentations or
whether the actors involved in these conflicts
constructed their argumentation mainly around other
frames that do not focus primarily on the propertization
of immaterial goods. The goal of the article is to judge
the relative importance of the ideas of the public
domain and the commons in current conflicts of the
knowledge society.
On the following pages I will first briefly introduce the
data sources and methods used to identify the frames
employed by the actors. I will then discuss the two
conflicts separately, starting with the access to
medicines mobilization, because it represents the
broader conflict of the two. The article closes with a
more general comparative discussion of the framing
strategies and how they should be interpreted.
Data and methods
For the analysis of the actors’ framing
strategies, I draw on empirical data originally
collected in a larger project about conflict in the
knowledge society (Haunss 2013). More specifically,
in the access to medicines conflict, the analysis is
based on 30 documents published by core actors
involved in the conflict. These documents were coded
in a qualitative content analysis (Kelle, Prein
& Bird 1995; Titscher, Meyer, Wodak & Vetter
2000) in which passages were identified that
represent the actors’ diagnostic, prognostic and
motivational frames (Snow & Benford 1988). The
coding used the qualitative data analysis package
RQDA (Huang 2010). Based on this coding, it is
possible to identify the master frames of each of
the two camps. I methodically followed Gerhards’ and
Rucht’s approach to analyzing mesomobilization
processes, i.e. mobilization and negotiation
processes among groups mobilizing in a common
campaign (Gerhards & Rucht 1992). Similar to
their study, my main interest was to identify
elements of the collective action frames that help
the actors of a heterogeneous network to develop a
common interpretation and action strategy.
The analysis in the software patents conflict is
based on a broader document corpus. Because of the
more limited geographical scope of the software
patents conflict, it was possible to base the
analysis on the content coding of 124 newspaper
articles published in quality newspapers in Germany,
Great Britain, France and Poland between 1997 and
2005.1 As a first step,
all articles mentioning the software patents
conflict in Europe or the issue of software patents
in general were selected. In these articles every
instance of claims-making was coded according to a
coding scheme (Haunss & Kohlmorgen 2008) that is
a further development of Koopmans’ political claims
analysis codebook (Koopmans 2002). A claim
in this context means any demand, proposal,
criticism, decision, etc. made by actors active in
the respective field of conflict in the form of
statements or collective mobilizations. This
can be a parliamentary motion, a formal vote, a
petition, a demonstration or any other act of public
political intervention. For each claim, the content
of the claim, the date, name and organizational
affiliation of the claimant, addressees (if
explicitly mentioned) and the argumentative frame
were recorded. Frames in this context are
the reasons that are given for a specific instance
of claims-making. They are the – sometimes explicit,
often implicit – arguments or concepts used by the
actors. To give an example: An article reports that
an actor has published a press release in which he
demands that the European Parliament should reject
the directive, because it would disadvantage small
IT companies. This article contains a claim – the
press release – and a frame – “Software patents are
bad because they negatively affect the
competitiveness of small and medium sized
enterprises”. In the database this is then
coded as actor X making a claim (publishing a press
release), using the frame “competitiveness of SMEs”.
It is furthermore recorded that the frame
“competitiveness of SMEs” is here used to argue
against software patents in Europe. Overall, the 124
articles contained 338 claims for which a clear
actor position in the conflict was given. The
original dataset covers statements from all actors
present in the conflict, those in favor of stronger
intellectual property rights and those struggling
against far-reaching pharmaceutical patents in the
developing world and against software patents in
Europe. The following analysis only draws on the
statements from oppositional actors, since my focus
here is limited to the opponents of strong
intellectual property rights.
Access
to medicines On a global
level, the broadest and
most prominent conflict
about intellectual
property rights was
certainly the conflict
about access to
(essential) medicines.
At its core it was, and
still is, a conflict
about the effects of
patents for
pharmaceutical products
on access to drugs for
patients living in
countries of the Global
South. The conflict was
fueled, in particular,
by the issue of access
to HIV/AIDS medication
(for a more detailed
discussion, see Reis,
Terto & Pimenta
2009; ’t Hoen 2009;
Haunss 2013: Chapter 5).
The coordinates for this
conflict were set by the
dual dynamics of an
accelerating rate of HIV
infections in a number
of developing countries
in Africa, Asia and
South America and a
ratcheting up of IP
protection that
culminated in the 1995
TRIPS agreement. Medical
advances have, for many
patients in the Global
North, converted AIDS in
the 21st century from a
deadly illness to a
manageable chronic
disease (Osborn 2008).
But for most patients in
the Global South, this
is not yet the case. By
the end of the 1990s,
about one-third of the
world’s population did
not have access to
essential medicines, and
often even no access to
primary health care. One
reason for this is that
many countries lack the
necessary medical
infrastructure. But even
where this
infrastructure exists,
essential drugs are
often simply
unaffordable for many
people in the world’s
poor countries. This is
the epidemiological
backdrop against which
several NGOs started a
campaign for access to
essential medicines in
the late 1990s.
The second thread of
this conflict goes back
to the Uruguay Round of
world trade
negotiations. The
Uruguay Round of
multilateral trade
negotiations started in
1986 and ended nine
years later with the
transformation of the
General Agreement on
Tariffs and Trade (GATT)
into the World Trade
Organization (WTO). One
part of the negotiations
was a multilateral
agreement on
Trade-Related Aspects of
Intellectual Property
Rights (TRIPS) that was
included in the final
WTO treaty and went into
force on 1 January 1995.
TRIPS marked an
important change in
international IP
politics, as it shifted
responsibility for IP
issues from WIPO and
other UN agencies to the
WTO. All TRIPS member
states are required to
guarantee in their
national legislation a
number of minimum
standards of IP
protection, among them a
minimum copyright term
of 50 years after the
death of the author, a
minimum patent term of
20 years (Art. 12) and a
clause that patents must
be granted “in all
fields of technology”
(Art. 27–33) – including
pharmaceutical products.
For many countries this
meant far-reaching
changes to their patent
legislations, and in the
field of pharmaceutical
patents it foreclosed
the option of process
patents that some
developing countries,
notably India, had
chosen until then, and
which had allowed them
to produce cheap generic
versions of brand name
medicines. Because the
actual synthetization of
a medicine’s active
ingredient is usually
not overly complex in
the pharmaceutical
production process,
process patents allow
firms to analyze the
chemical composition of
pharmaceuticals
available on the market,
and then develop an
alternative process2
to produce a drug with
the same chemical
structure. TRIPS
eliminated this option.
Instead, all countries
are now required to
introduce product
patents in all fields of
technology, including
pharmaceuticals, and to
guarantee a 20-year
minimum patent term.
This is the global IP
backdrop of the access
to essential medicines
campaign.
The
goal of the access to medicines campaign was, and
still is, to provide patients in the Global South with
the drugs they need to fight the most dangerous
illnesses, above all HIV/AIDS. The access to medicines
campaign started as an NGO mobilization in 1996 with a
meeting of several health NGOs in Bielefeld, Germany,
where the issue of access to medicines was discussed
for the first time in a broader civil society context
(Schaaber 2006). At about the same time,
Thailand and South Africa were confronted with massive
pressure from the United States when they began to
draft laws to incorporate the flexibilities the TRIPS
agreement still allowed into their national
legislation, with the result that Thailand quickly
abandoned their plans and in South Africa, the law was
immediately challenged before the High Court by the
South African Pharmaceutical Manufacturers’
Association (PMA) and 39 pharmaceutical companies for
allegedly being unconstitutional (Sell 2002; Cameron
& Berger 2005). A number of developing countries,
supported by an NGO network, made another attempt to
put a resolution on the agenda of the 1998 World
Health Assembly (WHA). This resolution urged WHO
member states “to ensure that public health rather
than commercial interests have primacy in
pharmaceutical and health policies and to review their
options under the Agreement on Trade Related Aspects
of Intellectual Property Rights to safeguard access to
essential drugs” (World Health Organization 1998) and
was also met with fierce opposition from US and
international pharmaceutical associations, who were
supported by the United States and several European
countries (Sell 2002: 504).
In 1999 the conflict gained international publicity,
with Médecins Sans Frontières (MSF) joining the NGO
coalition and starting its own campaign.3
MSF’s specific advantage was that it already had very
high public visibility in countries of the Global
North. MSF also had a very high level of moral
credibility, having been awarded the Nobel Peace Prize
in 1999, and the organization is a large buyer of
essential medicines, which it distributes in its
medical aid projects in the developing world.
In the following years, several other NGOs joined the
network. In their campaign for access to medicines
they employed a broad arsenal of action forms. They
provided expertise to developing countries’
administrations and governments, lobbied northern
countries to counter the position of industry
lobbyists, organized meetings and conferences,
published information material, and organized rallies
and demonstrations in countries of both the Global
North and South.
The biggest success of the mobilization was the Doha
Declaration on TRIPS and Public Health at the
WTO ministerial meeting in November 2001, in which the
member states declared that
the TRIPS Agreement does not and should
not prevent Members from taking measures to protect
public health. Accordingly, while reiterating our
commitment to the TRIPS Agreement, we affirm that
the Agreement can and should be interpreted and
implemented in a manner supportive of WTO Members’
right to protect public health and, in particular,
to promote access to medicines for all. (WTO 2001)
The Doha Declaration also recognized the so-called
“Paragraph 6 problem,” in which TRIPS allows
compulsory licenses predominantly for the supply of
the domestic market in Article 31(f). Negotiations to
solve this problem showed a continuing deep rift
between developing countries on one side and the USA
and Europe on the other (’t Hoen 2009). An agreement
which was reached in the WTO General Council in 2003
and reaffirmed in 2005 (WTO 2003, 2005) de facto
narrows the scope of the Doha Declaration and installs
a highly complex rule set that many NGOs dismiss as
unworkable (Cameron & Berger 2005; Médecins Sans
Frontières 2006).
The access to medicines conflict also played out at
the local level in numerous campaigns in South Africa,
India, Brazil, Thailand and other countries. It was
thus a true transnational and multi-level
mobilization, combining lobbying, information
campaigns, demonstrations and the creation of
counter-expertise at the national and international
level, within and outside organizations. During the
conflict, a collective actor emerged from a network of
local and transnational NGOs, engaged individuals,
government officials from some countries of the Global
South and other actors that brought various issues
together and connected mobilizations at various
levels. The mobilization connected local protests,
like the demonstrations in Thailand against the
US-Thailand free trade agreement and for compulsory
licenses for HIV/AIDS drugs, transnational protest
campaigns, like the one against pharmaceutical
lobbyists in South Africa, and lobby politics at
international organizations, like the work for the WTO
Doha Declaration.
What was the argumentative kit holding this network
together? Which frames were developed to mobilize and
unite such a diverse coalition? What role did the idea
of the public domain play in the discourse about
access to medicines? Table 1
summarizes the frames used in core documents of the
most important organizations involved in the
mobilization for access to medicines.
Table 1: Frames used in the
access to medicines conflict
Not very surprisingly, the actors involved in the
access to medicines mobilization identify
international trade and the exclusive rights that
patents confer as the core problems restricting access
to medicines in the Global South, and they argue that
health should have primacy over economic interests.
The overall narrative of the access to medicines
coalition can be summarized as follows (Haunss 2013:
175):
The problem is that millions of people have no
access to essential medicines.
The main reason for this lack of access is that
the prices for those drugs are much too high in
the developing world.
The cause for these high prices is a market
failure: Drug production is driven by profit
margins and not by public health needs.
Intellectual property rights aggravate the problem
by prohibiting competition, and trade
liberalization forces developing countries to
introduce and/or strengthen these intellectual
property rights that are detrimental to public
health.
The problems can only be solved if public health
concerns are given primacy over private economic
interests.
To solve the access problem, developing
countries should use compulsory licenses, promote
generic competition and allow parallel imports.
More generally, developing countries should make
use of the TRIPS flexibilities. The transition
period should be extended and a moratorium should
prevent developed countries from using the dispute
settlement mechanism against TRIPS violations in
relation to access to medicines.
To address the problem more comprehensively, the
TRIPS agreement should be reformed and northern
countries should refrain from including TRIPS-plus
clauses in bilateral or regional trade agreements.
Alternative mechanisms should be introduced to
strengthen research and development of drugs for
the needs of developing countries (Neglected
Diseases Act, Medical Patent Pool), and additional
financial resources should be provided to help
developing countries to cope with the problem.
The first three points represent the diagnostic frame
of the access to medicines coalition. Points four to
seven are the prognostic frames in which actors define
what to do. The motivational framing relies on the
urgency of the health problem.
The framing of the access to medicines coalition is
obviously not centered on the idea of the public
domain. The argumentation instead focuses on the
primacy of health over economic considerations,
claiming that the production and distribution of
medicines should primarily focus on the goal of
combating serious illnesses and helping patients. The
argumentation contradicts the general economic
assumption that markets automatically lead to
innovation and an optimal allocation of resources.
Instead, the access to medicines coalition argues that
markets may well lead to innovation, not necessarily
in the areas where innovation would be most needed due
to pressing health problems, but in areas where
medical innovations are most profitable. Market
processes alone are therefore not well suited to
establish access to essential medicines – especially
in poor countries. This contradicts the standard
assumption behind the continuing expansion of
intellectual property rights, that the solution for
the so-called tragedy of the commons (Hardin 1968),
and thus the most effective way to maximize
innovation, would be the privatization of knowledge.
While the public domain is not mentioned explicitly in
the framing of the access to medicines coalition, the
idea nevertheless plays a role in at least two of the
frames used by members of the coalition. The
argumentation for compulsory licenses and for a global
patent pool both refer to policies which would secure
public access to the knowledge necessary for the
production of essential medicines, at least in the
Global South. And the idea for an alternative to the
existing global patent system indeed found some
support within the UN system, and in 2010 the
“Medicines Patent Pool” was founded as a UN-backed
organization. Patent holders, and in particular
private pharmaceutical companies, can grant the
Medicines Patent Pool (MPP) a nonexclusive license for
their essential medicines. The MPP can then sublicense
other firms to produce these drugs for patients in
developing countries (Cox 2012).
Coming back to Boyle’s suggestion that a movement
against the growing propertization of knowledge should
develop a mobilization frame centered around the idea
of the public domain, we can see that in the largest
and most transnational mobilization against the
current expansion of intellectual property rights to
date, the idea of the public domain plays a role but
has not provided an overarching master frame for the
mobilization. This may be a consequence of the
idiosyncrasies of the specific case. The individual
right to health has a strong normative value, and the
claim that pharmaceutical profit interests would
deprive patients in the Global South of this right
creates an easily communicable injustice frame (Olesen
2015), well suited for winning support for the cause
of the access to medicines coalition. This option is
not as plausible in the case of software patents,
where no human rights of vulnerable populations are
touched. In the next section I will therefore analyze
the framing in the second most prominent recent
conflict about intellectual property rights, which
surprisingly developed around an issue that – before
the conflict – most commentators would not have seen
as a candidate for a large-scale protest mobilization:
software patents.
Software
patents The conflict
over software patents in
Europe – from its
beginning in 1997 to its
end in 2005 – involved a
large number of actors
and brought the former
specialist issue into
TV’s evening news. The
conflict started in June
1997 when the European
Commission published a
Green Paper on the
Community patent and the
patent system in Europe
(COM 1997). It ended
eight years later on 6
June 2005 when the
European Parliament
rejected the “Directive
on the Patentability of
Computer-Implemented
Inventions” (COM 2002)
with a majority of 648
to 14 votes. Between
these dates lay a
contentious
mobilization, in which
new collective actors
emerged and entered the
arena of IP politics in
Europe, and which has
lastingly altered the
power relations in this
field. The goal of the
diverse coalition of
actors mobilizing
against the directive
was effectively to make
the patenting of
software impossible in
Europe.
The goal of the
Commission was to create
a sound legal basis for
granting software
patents in Europe.
Patents for software
became available in the
US in the 1990s (Jaffe
2000) and have since
been extensively used by
the industry and
forcefully criticized by
academics for breaking
the patent system (Jaffe
& Lerner 2004;
Bessen & Meurer
2008). The problem with
software patents is
that, compared to the
traditional copyright
protection of the
program code, software
patents offer an
additional and much
broader option to create
exclusive rights.
Copyrights create
exclusive rights only
for the specific code of
a program. If another
program creates the same
functionality with
different code it
therefore does not
violate existing
copyrights. Patents, on
the other hand, can
create exclusive rights
for a certain
functionality,
independent of the
specific code used to
realize this
functionality. For two
reasons it is often hard
to determine whether or
not a new piece of
software may infringe on
an existing software
patent. First, given the
complexity of most
current software and the
sheer number of patents,
it is almost impossible
for the average software
programmer to reliably
judge whether or not new
software may possibly
violate an existing
patent. Second, this is
aggravated by the
tendency to formulate
patent claims to be as
fuzzy as possible in
order to maximize the
scope of a given patent.
In Europe, the European
Patent Convention
disallows patents for
software “as such” in
Article 52. But in the
practice of the European
Patent Office (EPO),
this limitation has been
interpreted very loosely
so that the EPO now de
facto grants software
patents as long as the
patent claim also
mentions the hardware on
which the software is
run (Laub 2006).
Nevertheless, because
patents still have to be
enforced on the national
level, and because not
all national courts in
EU member countries
follow the liberal
interpretation of the
EPO, the actual value of
EPO-granted software
patents for firms is
often not clear
(Ballardini 2008).
Intensive
lobbying and various forms of protest accompanied the
drafting of the directive and the ensuing legislative
process. Proponents of software patents and of the
directive proposed by the Commission were mainly
national and international business associations and
large ICT firms. Opponents came mainly from the Free
and Open Source Software (FOSS) sector, supported by
civil society organizations and small and medium sized
enterprises (SME) business associations.
The conflict was characterized by dense, informal
cooperation networks within each camp and a strong
polarization between proponents and opponents of
software patents. Opponents of software patents staged
demonstrations in Brussels, Strasbourg, and in several
cities in the member states, as well as virtual
demonstrations on the Internet. Both sides used
electronic media to lobby the members of the European
Parliament and to publicize their claims and
positions.
The fault lines did not run along existing cleavages
of the industrial age. It was neither possible to
locate the two camps along a left-right axis, nor was
it a capital-labor conflict, or a conflict between
industry interest and other (e.g. civil society)
groups. All political parties in the European
Parliament – except the Greens – were split on the
issue of software patents, and while civil society
organizations sided with the opponents, the majority
of the oppositional actors were corporate actors
themselves.
I have elsewhere (Haunss 2013; Haunss & Kohlmorgen
2010; Leifeld & Haunss 2012) provided a detailed
discussion of the development of the conflict and an
explanation of the surprising success of the
comparatively resource-poor coalition of software
patent opponents. These topics are not the focus of
this paper. The interesting aspect here is what kind
of frames the opponents used to argue and mobilize
against software patents. Did they invoke the notion
of the public domain in their fight against a further
extension of patentability of immaterial goods? Or did
they construct their mobilizing frames around other
concepts?
Table 2 gives an overview of
the frames used by opponents of software patents. It
shows that – as in the access to medicines conflict –
claims against software patents were not mainly framed
by referring to the notion of a public domain. In
their fight against software patents, the actors
involved in the conflict framed their demands against
software patents above all by arguing that software
patents would diminish the competitiveness of SMEs,
that they would impede innovation and transfer of
knowledge, and that software patents would lead to
monopolization in the ICT sector. They also criticized
the Commission’s ignorance of objections voiced by a
large number of software patent opponents and by the
majority of the members of the European Parliament as
disrespect for democratic procedures in favor of
narrow lobby interests. Together these four frames
were used in more than two thirds (67.4 %) of the
claims in which arguments were given for the
opposition to software patents.4
Table 2: Frames used in the
software patents conflict
Claims that are supported by arguments about the value
of open source software and – more generally – of open
access to knowledge and information are present in the
opponents’ framing repertoire, but they make up only
about 8 percent of the frames. Thus, instead of
focusing on the idea of the public domain and the
principles of open source and open access which would
serve to create a public domain in the area of
computer software, the opponents constructed a clear
storyline centered around innovation: Innovation in
the IT sector would depend mainly on small firms and
individual programmers whose livelihood (or business
model) would be threatened by the directive. Software
patents would have a negative effect on innovation in
the IT sector and should therefore not be allowed in
Europe. This core story was embedded in anti-monopoly
and pro-democracy arguments. It contained a clear call
for action (“Stop software patents!”) and a strong
motivational element (“Defend our livelihood!”), and
thus provided a viable base for a collective identity
of the activists involved in the mobilization.
The
role of the public
domain in IP
conflicts Similar to the
constellation in the
access to medicines
conflict, the idea of
the public domain in the
software patents
conflict did not provide
a master frame for the
mobilization but
structured a
sub-narrative about
alternatives to the
current system of strong
and exclusive
intellectual property
rights. The idea of the
public domain – although
not the term itself – is
thus an important
element in the actors’
framing, but it does not
play the role James
Boyle suggested. Health,
development, innovation
and democracy are
instead frames that
actors have chosen to
mobilize against the
current system of
extensive intellectual
property rights and
attempts to further
strengthen the scope of
protection. Even though
my analysis here builds
only on two cases –
albeit the most
prominent ones – I would
argue that the low
salience of the public
domain in the two
conflicts is not a
result of the case
selection but an
expression of the more
general conflict lines
along which conflicts
about the production,
appropriation and
distribution of
knowledge have developed
and most likely will
develop in the future.
Boyle’s narrative of
intellectual property
rights as a second
enclosure focuses on the
process of
propertization:
knowledge that
originally is not
private property is
transformed into
property through
intellectual property
rights. Against this
propertization, the idea
of the public domain
somehow defends a
natural state of
knowledge, which is
still free for use by
everybody and therefore
is not (yet) property.
The idea of the public
domain therefore at
least partially contains
a defensive element. The
public domain is
something that already
exists or has to be
recreated, and that has
to be defended against
encroachment by the
processes of
propertization, which
removes ever greater
parts from the public
domain.
In the two cases
discussed here, such a
defensive argumentation
is present but not
dominant. Instead the
focus lies in the
production of knowledge.
This points to the
limits of the enclosure
metaphor for
understanding knowledge
society conflicts. While
intellectual property
rights can restrict
access to knowledge just
as fences restrict
access to land,
knowledge – in contrast
to land – can be
endlessly reproduced and
expanded. Therefore, not
(only) the
propertization of
existing knowledge but
the production of new
knowledge is the crucial
element – or at least
production of new
knowledge is the element
that the actors involved
in the conflicts focus
on much more than the
public domain. The rules
that govern the
production of knowledge
determine who has access
to this knowledge and
under which conditions.
And therefore the
production of knowledge
is central to the IP
conflicts. I argue that
both the conflict over
access to medicines and
the conflict over
software patents
directly address this
issue as a conflict
about the appropriate
mode of innovation, i.e.
a conflict about which
set of social mechanisms
should determine how and
where new knowledge is
produced.
Two perspectives stand
in opposition: the
industrial mode vs. a
decentralized mode of
innovation. The
industrialized mass
production of the
industrial era is
accompanied by
industrialized mass
innovation – innovation
that is concentrated in
large industrial units,
be they large private or
public research labs.
The current patent
system fits this
centralized and
industrialized mode of
innovation well, and is
directly challenged by
the current IP
conflicts. Opponents of
software patents have
argued that without
software patents, the
“real” innovators of the
European high-tech
sector would not be the
handful of large
transnational
corporations who make
extensive use of the
patent system, but the
many thousands of small-
and medium-sized
software and technology
companies, who would
rather suffer than
profit from patent
protection in the area
of software.
In the access to
medicines conflict, the
industrial innovation
model has been
challenged from a
different angle. The
core criticism here was
not so much that the big
pharmaceutical companies
would not be the “real”
innovators, but that the
innovation would not
create the most urgently
needed knowledge.
Instead of producing
drugs for the wealthiest
patients, innovation
should be geared to
producing drugs against
the most dangerous
illnesses. Public
authorities should
therefore be able to
intervene and redirect
innovation processes and
make existing drugs
available according to
human needs.
Both conflicts also
challenge the industrial
innovation model on
another level. The
social movement actors
involved in the conflict
insisted that knowledge
policies and innovation
processes should not be
determined through
market processes, but by
the people and/or
accountable and
democratically
legitimized
institutions. An
alternative vision of a
decentralized and
democratic mode of
innovation emerged from
these conflicts. The
idea of the public
domain is highly
compatible with this
mode of innovation but
does not guide the
actors’ argumentative
strategies.
In sum, the idea of the
public domain did not
provide an overarching
master frame, either
because actors did not
realize its potential or
because they were not
aware of it. The public
domain is simply not the
metaphor that is best
suited to frame a
conflict about the rules
for the production of
knowledge. Moreover, the
activists involved in
the two IP conflicts
discussed here do not
reject the idea of
intellectual property as
such. They argue that
the granting of property
rights should require
demanding social
obligations for the
property holders, just
as material property
rights in social market
economies also (at least
ideally) entail societal
duties for the property
holders.
Notes
1
The newspapers
from which the
articles were
taken are, in
Germany:
Süddeutsche
Zeitung, die
tageszeitung,
Frankfurter
Rundschau, Die
Welt,
Stuttgarter
Zeitung; in
the UK: Daily
Mail, The
Times, The
Guardian,
Financial
Times, Western
Mail, Morning
Star, The
Daily
Telegraph, The
Business, The
Independent,
The Observer;
in France: Le
Figaro,
Liberation,
Les Echos, Le
Monde, La
Tribune; and
in Poland
Gazeta
Wyborcza,
Polityka,
Rzeczpospolita,
Wprost. 2
India’s
process
patents-only
policy de
facto followed
the Swiss
example. Until
1977,
Switzerland
only had
pharmaceutical
process
patents and
introduced
product
patents only
after its
pharmaceutical
industry was
well
established
(Boldrin &
Levine 2008:
216). 3http://www.msfaccess.org/ 4
In 31.4
percent of the
pro- and
contra
statements, no
explicit frame
accompanied
the actor’s
positioning
against or for
software
patents.
References
Ballardini,
R. M. (2008).
Software
Patents in
Europe: The
Technical
Requirement
Dilemma. Journal
of
Intellectual
Property Law
Practice
3(9):
563–575, Crossref
Bessen,
J. and Meurer,
M. J. (2008).
Patent
Failure: How
Judges,
Bureaucrats,
and Lawyers
Put Innovators
at Risk.
Princeton,
Princeton
University
Press.
Boldrin, M.
and Levine, D.
K. (2008). Against
Intellectual
Monopoly.
New York,
Cambridge
University
Press.
Boyle,
J. (2003). The
Second
Enclosure
Movement and
the
Construction
of the Public
Domain. Law
and
Contemporary
Problems
66(1&2):
33–74, Crossref
Cameron,
E. and Berger,
J. (2005).
Patents and
Public Health:
Principle,
Politics and
Paradox. Proceedings
of the British
Academy
131: 331–369,
Crossref
COM.
(1997). Promoting
Innovation
through
Patents. Green
Paper on the
Community
Patent and the
Patent System
in Europe.
COM (1997) 314
final,
Brussels,
Commission of
the European
Communities.
Retrieved
November 28,
2008, from http://europa.eu/documents /comm/green_papers/pdf/com97_314_en.pdf
COM.
(2002). Proposal
for a
Directive of
the European
Parliament and
of the Council
on the
Patentability
of
Computer-Implemented
Inventions.
COM (2002) 92,
Brussels,
Commission of
the European
Communities.
Retrieved
March 25,
2016, from http://eur- lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/?uri=COM:2002:0092:FIN
Cox,
K. L. (2012).
The Medicines
Patent Pool:
Promoting
Access and
Innovation for
Life-Saving
Medicines
Through
Voluntary
Licenses. Hastings
Science &
Technology Law
Journal
4(2): 293–325,
Crossref
Dusollier,
S. (2006). The
Master’s Tools
v. The
Master’s
House:
Creative
Commons v.
Copyright. Columbia
Journal of Law
& the Arts
29(3):
271–293.
Gerhards,
J. and Rucht,
D. (1992).
Mesomobilization:
Organizing and
Framing in Two
Protest
Campaigns in
West Germany.
American
Journal of
Sociology
98(3):
555–596, Crossref
Hardin,
G. (1968). The
Tragedy of the
Commons. Science
162(3859):
1243–1248, Crossref
Haunss,
S. (2013). Conflicts
in the
Knowledge
Society. The
Contentious
Politics of
Intellectual
Property.
Cambridge,
Cambridge
University
Press.
Haunss,
S. and
Kohlmorgen, L.
(2008). Codebook
for the
Analysis of
Political
Claims in
Conflicts on
Intellectual
Property
Rights in
Europe.
Retrieved
January 19,
2009, from http://www.ipgovernance.eu /publications/IPGovCodebook.pdf
Haunss,
S. and
Kohlmorgen, L.
(2010).
Conflicts
about
Intellectual
Property
Claims: The
Role and
Function of
Collective
Action
Networks. Journal
of European
Public Policy
17(2):
242–262, Crossref
Haunss,
S. and
Shadlen, K.
C., eds.
(2009).
Politics of
Intellectual
Property.
Contestation
over the
Ownership,
Use, and
Control of
Knowledge and
Information.
Cheltenham,
Glos, Edward
Elgar
Publishing.
’t
Hoen, E.
(2009). The
Global
Politics of
Pharmaceutical
Monopoly
Power. Drug
Patents,
Access,
Innovation and
the
Application of
the WTO Doha
Declaration on
TRIPS and
Public Health.
Diemen, AMB.
Huang,
R. (2010). RQDA:
R-based
Qualitative
Data Analysis.
R package
version
0.1-9,.
Retrieved July
13, 2011, from
http://rqda.r-forge.r- project.org/
Jaffe,
A. B. (2000).
The U.S.
Patent System
in Transition:
Policy
Innovation and
the Innovation
Process. Research
Policy
29(4-5):
531–557, Crossref
Jaffe,
A. B. and
Lerner, J.
(2004). Innovation
and Its
Discontents:
How Our Broken
Patent System
is Endangering
Innovation and
Progress, and
What to Do
About It.
Princeton, NJ,
Princeton
Univ. Press.
Kelle,
U., Prein, G.
and Bird, K.
(1995). Computer-Aided
Qualitative
Data Analysis:
Theory,
Methods and
Practice.
Thousand Oaks,
CA, Sage.
Laub,
C. (2006).
Software
Patenting:
Legal
Standards in
Europe and the
US in view of
Strategic
Limitations of
the IP
Systems. The
Journal of
World
Intellectual
Property 9(3):
344–372, Crossref
Leifeld,
P. and Haunss,
S. (2012).
Political
Discourse
Networks and
the Conflict
over Software
Patents in
Europe. European
Journal of
Political
Research
51(3):
382–409, Crossref
Olesen,
T. (2015). Global
Injustice
Symbols and
Social
Movements.
New York,
Palgrave
Macmillan.
Osborn,
J. E. (2008).
The Past,
Present, and
Future of
AIDS. Journal
of the
American
Medical
Association
300(5):
581–583, Crossref
Ostrom,
E. (1990). Governing
the Commons:
The Evolution
of
Institutions
for Collective
Action.
Cambridge,
Cambridge
University
Press.
Reis,
R., Terto, V.,
Jr. and
Pimenta, M.
C., eds.
(2009). Intellectual
Property
Rights and
Access to ARV
Medicines.
Civil Society
Resistance in
the Global
South. Rio
de Janeiro,
ABIA.
Schaaber,
J. (2006). Eine
kleine
Chronologie.
25 Jahre BUKO
Pharma-Kampagne. Bielefeld, BUKO Pharma-Kampagne.
Sell,
S. K. (2002).
TRIPS and the
Access to
Medicines
Campaign. Wisconsin
International
Law Journal
20(3):
481–522.
Snow,
D. A. and
Benford, R. D.
(1988).
Ideology,
Frame
Resonance, and
Participant
Mobilization.
In From
Structure to
Action.
Comparing
Social
Movement
Research
Across
Cultures,
eds Bert
Klandermans
Hanspeter
Kriesi and
Sidney Tarrow.
JAI, pp.
197–217.
Snow,
D. A. and
Benford, R. D.
(1992). Master
Frames and
Cycles of
Protest. In Frontiers
in social
movement
theory,
eds Adlon D.
Morris and
Carol McClurg
Mueller. New
Haven, CT,
Yale
University,
pp. 133–155.
Titscher,
S., Meyer, M.,
Wodak, R. and
Vetter, E.
(2000). Methods
of Text and
Discourse
Analysis.
London, Sage.
World
Health
Organization.
(1998). Revised
Drug Strategy
(Draft).
EB101.R24,
World Health
Organization.
WTO.
(2003).
Decision of
the General
Council of 30
August 2003:
Implementation
of paragraph 6
of the Doha
Declaration on
the TRIPS
Agreement and
public health.
Retrieved
August 19,
2010, from http://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/trips_e/implem_para6_e.htm