Department of Philosophy, UiT The Arctic University of
Norway, oyvind.stokke@uit.no
Introduction
Thomas Pogge is Leitner Professor of
Philosophy and International Affairs and Director of
the Global Justice Program at Yale University,
Professor of Political Philosophy at the Centre for
Professional Ethics of the University of Central
Lancashire and Research Director at the Centre for the
Study of Mind in Nature at the University of Oslo. His
life and career have been dedicated to understanding
what economic and political factors drive poverty and
how poverty worldwide might be defeated. Pogge is a
member of the Norwegian Academy of Science and Letters
as well as co-founder of Academics Stand
Against Poverty (www.academicsstand.org), an
international network aiming to enhance the impact of
scholars, teachers and students on global poverty, and
of Incentives
for Global Health, a team effort toward
developing a complement to the pharmaceutical patent
regime that would improve access to advanced medicines
for the poor worldwide (www.healthimpactfund.org). In
2012-13, he chaired the Task Force on Illicit Financial
Flows, Poverty and Human Rights of the International Bar
Association’s Human Rights Institute (IBAHRI). In 2013,
his article “Are We Violating the Human Rights of the
World’s Poor?” was awarded the Gregory Kavka Prize in
Political Philosophy.2
Pogge’s recent publications include: Politics as Usual:
What Lies behind the Pro-Poor Rhetoric, 2010, and
World Poverty and
Human Rights, 2nd edition, 2008, both published by
Polity Press. In 2008, he also co-edited, with Darrel
Moellendorf and Keith Horton respectively, Global Justice
and Global Ethics,
two volumes of seminal essays published by Paragon
House.3
Pogge’s
proposals have strong relevance for political
philosophers—who are concerned with examining
possibilities for changing the institutional structures
that produce global inequalities—and also to policy
makers, who can apply his reasoning to real world
situations. Pogge has insightfully criticized the
current patent system for depriving the poor of access
to advanced medicines. To solve this problem, he
proposes to create an option for pharmaceutical
innovators to be rewarded, from public funds, according
to the health impact of their innovation on condition
that they sell it at cost.4
Another of his innovative proposals is a Global
Resources Dividend (GRD) that would charge states for
the use of the Earth’s natural resources, such as oil,
gas and water, and for polluting the natural environment
by discharging waste into soil, water and air. GRD
revenues would fund development in the world’s poor
regions,5
thus enabling the world’s poor to obtain a fairer share
of the Earth, which in principle belongs to all human
beings. In addition to these proposals, Pogge has
recently been working on creating a more adequate
measure for tracking poverty and gender disparities6
and on promoting the curtailment of illicit financial
flows facilitated by tax havens, secrecy jurisdictions
and shell companies.7
His proposals are ambitious in their ideals and deeply
philosophical. At the same time, Pogge’s proposals are
often supported by strong empirical data and statistical
analyses, offering evidence for the need to modify
actual laws and policies.
In the following interview, Pogge focuses his attention
on the situation in Brazil, a country that he says can
exert its increasing influence on the design of global
institutions. He anticipates the challenges coming for
Brazil in combating poverty and gender disparities. He
discusses the positive and negative aspects of the Bolsa Família programme,
and he suggests that the government should extend its
benefits to a larger proportion of the population in
order to gain more support from the public. He believes
the Bolsa
Família programme is well-designed and that its
implementation is essential to mitigating the absurd
inequalities that so strongly polarize society and
jeopardize democracy in Brazil. To distribute resources
to the poor is not a question of charity, as it was
considered in the old days, he explains. He finds no
justification for affluent Brazilians to control all the
country’s resources while the poor are deprived of their
fair share. Pogge is also concerned that, owing to
increasing capital mobility, globalization will tend to
benefit Brazil’s rich, who also find it much easier to
evade taxes. Therefore, in addition to the intervention
of social programmes, Pogge recommends that the
Brazilian government ensure that the country’s wealth is
properly taxed and distributed.
I. Structural Poverty, Social Justice, and
the Bolsa Família programme in Brazil
Duarte: I will start
by citing a provocative sentence from your book:“Even a mere
80 years ago, the poor and unemployed were still
often seen as lazy and delinquent merely on the
ground that others of equally humble origins had
risen from dishwasher to millionaire” (Pogge
2010: 16).
When discussing interactional and institutional
moral duties, you believe that decades ago, people
“did not understand the structural constraints on
social mobility” (Pogge 2010: 16), implying that
poverty is in part a consequence of a lack of
opportunities and possibilities. According to you,
people often did not understand that this
structural poverty can be influenced by an
“intelligent redesign of the rules” and
institutions (Pogge 2010: 16). You cite the
Bolsa Família programme in Brazil as an example of
an intelligent institutional redesign toward the
promotion of social justice in a place where the
inequalities were enormous. Indeed, the Bolsa
Família programme seems to have accomplished its
goal when, according to the Brazilian government,
in February 2013, extreme poverty had officially
been eradicated from the country. Ten years after
the programme began, one-fourth of the population
benefits from it at a cost of a bit more than 0.5
per cent of the country’s GDP.8
Despite these positive results, a substantial part
of the Brazilian middle class aggressively attacks
the initiative. They consider the “family
allowance” to really be a “laziness grant”.
According to them, the programme has a pure
electoral purpose, promoting no real and long-term
benefits for the Brazilian population. Their
contention is, however, contradicted by several
studies showing positive results produced by the
implementation of the programme,9
as if they were eighty years late in this
discussion. My questions are: What could explain
such disconnection between the government and the
middle-class public opinion? Does the Brazilian
middle class truly have anything to fear?
Pogge: This disconnect between the
government and middle-class public opinion might be
explained by the fact that, in Brazil, the programme
does not benefit a majority of the population, but
only one-quarter of them. When a social safety net
was first instituted in the United States and in
Germany, for example, the benefits were enjoyable by
a majority of the population. These successful
examples show us how to build support for social
programmes: benefits must be enjoyable by the
majority of the electorate, at least to the extent
that they expect to derive significant benefit from
the programmes during some period of their life. But
such broad diffusion of benefit may be difficult to
achieve. Brazilian society is among the most unequal
in the world; and in a situation of extreme
inequality, it is difficult to construct social
programmes so that they benefit the majority of the
population. The needs of the extremely poor minority
are too urgent to allow dilution of these
programmes.
Ideally, we want the programme to cover at least
half the population because this could produce a
stable electoral majority in its support; but of
course we also want the programme to be focused on
really benefiting the needy, the poor. Without such
a focus, the programme becomes too expensive or too
diluted with regard to the very poor. In the case of
Brazil, the decision was in favour of a programme
that is more focused at the cost of being harder to
establish and defend politically. At a cost of half
a per cent of GDP, the Bolsa Família
programme benefits one-fourth of the population but
excludes a still-struggling segment of the middle
class that sees its contribution to the programme as
excessive and does not really want to pay for its
support of the poor. Such resentment must be
considered when designing this type of social
programme. It should be discussed with the society:
why should we pay for these benefits? How broad do
we want the programme to be? It should become clear
to the majority of Brazilians that, even though the
programme does not benefit them directly, they
nonetheless have reason to support it.
As regards the claim that this programme is a
benefit for “lazy” people—well, it might be, of
course. A programme can be badly designed; but, from
what I know, I do not think this is true of the Bolsa Família
programme. It has incentives attached to it, such as
immunizations, education, and female participation,
which produce actual benefits for the entire
country. If, for instance, families immunize their
children, then the country will save a considerable
amount of money on hospitalizations that would
otherwise have to be paid for by SUS, the Brazilian
public health system. Furthermore, the immunization
of children also averts or curtails the spread of
infectious diseases. Incentives to immunize one’s
children produce social benefits, benefits for all,
because anyone’s children are potentially at risk of
being infected by a child who was not immunized.
Such incentives are a public good, benefitting the
whole country and all its people. The same can be
said of education, which produces a more capable and
creative labour force, which in turn enables faster
and better economic development. Education also
produces a more critical and enlightened electorate,
which in turn results in a more sophisticated public
policy discourse and better governance and
administration. So a well-educated citizenry is also
a public good, a form of social capital that
enhances the economic opportunities and quality of
governance of all. This is especially obvious in the
case of women who have historically suffered grave
educational disadvantages: a society loses greatly
if it wastes the creativity and talents of most of
its women; and everyone gains when these assets are
developed and allowed to thrive. For all these
reasons, I am convinced that the characterization of
the Bolsa
Família programme as welfare for the lazy is
decidedly inappropriate.
In conclusion, let me say that I am commenting on
conditions in Brazil with some trepidation because I
recognize that, as an outsider, I am not as familiar
with the situation as many insiders are. So what I
say here should be read with this caution in mind.
II.
The Limits of Distributive Justice
Duarte: Imagining a situation
where everybody has their basic needs
fulfilled, but society still maintains large
social stratification and a low degree of
decommodification, how much would you say we
can claim for distributive justice?
Pogge: It is really important
for a country to have a spirit of community.
Inequality is corrosive. It affects our sense of
commitment to the common good, which is what makes
us feel we belong together and are all part of the
same society. Brazil is a good example of what
such corrosive effect of inequality can do to a
country. There is a real class division there,
which results in hostility between the rich and
the poor. Social stratification makes it more
difficult for a country to solve its problems
because the different groups cannot agree with one
another. Therefore, it is on the whole much better
to have less inequality rather than more
inequality, even when basic needs are ostensibly
fulfilled for all. Furthermore, a country has
better chances of establishing a successful
political system, a democratic political system,
when the interests of most people in regard to
institutional design and public policies are
reasonably well aligned. People will then think in
terms of what is best for their country rather
than in terms of what is best for their particular
social class. The latter thinking can lead to
divisive politics, which can deteriorate into a
kind of class warfare in which each side is trying
to woo the median voter, the middle class, in
order to win a majority of the electorate. When
political power shifts from one side to the other,
the winner will make fundamental changes to the
social institutions and policies that are most
relevant to the national income and wealth
distribution: to the tax system and to social
programmes. The winner may even try to change the
electoral system so as to make it harder for the
other side to regain political power. Such
fundamental changes back and forth are costly for
the country—just think of the cost of building up
some social programme with appropriate
administrative staff and then shutting it down
again a few years later. And the hostility and
nastiness of such politics is another great cost,
as we can see currently in the United States,
where the people’s confidence in the various
branches of government has all but disappeared. In
order to avoid such problems, in order to maintain
a harmonious democracy and an economy that
manifests solidarity and allows all citizens to
contribute according to their full potential, we
need to ensure that social and economic
inequalities remain reasonably small. This ensures
that the interests of the rich are not too sharply
opposed to those of the rest, that not too much is
at stake in such conflicts of interest and that
the rich are not so rich that they can corrupt the
political system and bend it to their will.
III. Distributive Justice
or Charity?
Duarte:
Currently, the distribution
of resources, opportunities,
or capabilities is usually
concentrated within national
borders. International
organizations attempting to
expand assistance
irrespective of national
borders, such as UNICEF, the
World Food Programme, and
Médecins Sans Frontières,
are often not financed by
taxes, but by charity. This
becomes problematic,
especially when the
continual demands of such
institutions provoke what
you call “fatigue, aversion,
and contempt (…) toward the
‘aid’ they dispense and its
recipients” (Pogge 2010:
55). How would your proposal
of a Global Resources
Dividend (Pogge 2008:
202-21) change this
relationship?
Pogge:
At least in the old days,
especially under the
perspective of the
centrality of the
nation-state, we thought
about measures to protect
the poor as charitable
measures. We saw gross
salaries as reflecting what
each person contributes to
the social product, and we
then saw it as charity when
the rich paid higher taxes
than the poor, thereby
shouldering a larger share
of the burden of maintaining
the institutions of
government. This perception
of charity was especially
compelling in regard to
government programmes that
disproportionately benefit
the poor. So the state was
defending a social and
economic order that
maintained great inequality
and was nonetheless
presented and perceived as
enforcing charity for the
poor at the expense of the
rich through
“redistributive” taxation.
The underlying picture here
is that the distribution of
income and wealth in a
society is the product of
two steps: at step 1, people
receive a share of the
social product that reflects
their contribution to it;
and at step 2, some of these
assets are charitably
redistributed by the state
so as to make the smaller
shares large enough to
sustain a minimally decent
life.
The fundamental flaw in this
picture is the
characterization of step 1.
Among the essential
contributions to the social
product are, for example,
material assets such as land
and natural resources. These
assets do not naturally
belong to their owners but
are assigned to them
pursuant to the rules of a
specific property system.
Such rules typically
prescribe that land can be
privately owned and
accumulated in unlimited
quantities, but they might
equally well prescribe that
land belongs to the
community and can be rented
for long periods through a
competitive bidding process.
The choice between such
alternative property regimes
has a profound impact on the
distribution of income and
wealth. Thus, while it is
true that a person’s
position in an existing
economic hierarchy depends
on his or her own efforts
(as well as, typically, on
those of his or her
ancestors), this position,
and the entire shape of the
distribution, also depend
profoundly on the ground
rules of the economy. This
insight undermines the idea
that the step1 distribution
is somehow a natural
reflection of the
contribution or merit of
individuals. And it thereby
also undermines the idea
that step 2 involves
charitable re-distribution.
Step 2 is better seen as an
integral part of the
existing property regime,
without which this regime
might be morally
unacceptable as well as
unable to maintain itself
politically.
Once we understand this
point, we are able to
rightly conceive that the
question is not about
redistributive justice,
where we have an initial
distribution that gets
rectified. Rather, the
question is simply about
distributive justice. In
this perspective, we ask:
how should an existing
social product be
distributed? How much should
go to landowners? Should
landowners be entitled to
the full amount they can
extract for contributing
their land to production or
only to some part thereof?
Then, when one society taxes
land holdings or the income
derived from land holdings,
it has an economic or
property system that is
different from that of
another country with
different ownership
conditions. Everyone who
owns land does so, from the
start, on the understanding
that the privilege of
ownership comes with certain
obligations. There is
nothing unjust about such
obligations as such—just
different ways of organizing
property rights and land
ownership.
The same points apply at the
international level, with
regard to my proposal of a
Global Resources Dividend,
for example. With such a GRD
in place, the privilege of
national domain over some
given territory is
understood, from the start,
as tied to each society’s
obligation to share with the
rest of humankind some of
the value of any territorial
resources it chooses to
exploit. Why should this not
be a perfectly sound
interpretation of the
plausible idea that the
Earth belongs to all human
beings in common? Think
hypothetically about human
beings taking stewardship of
this planet, knowing very
little about where its
valuable resources might be
located. What system of
national property should
they institute? There is no
natural or self-evident
answer to this question—no
natural facts we could rely
on to determine how the
world’s land should be
divided and what rights
exactly each society should
have over and within its
territory. It is an open
question how we should
regulate ownership rights
and decide who should get
what part of the value of
natural resources—an open
question to be decided in
light of considerations of
feasibility and efficiency,
of course, but also in light
of moral concerns and
arguments.
In thinking about which
rules to adopt, we should—in
part, at least—judge any
proposed system of rules on
the basis of its foreseeable
effects. Different systems
would have different
effects. The GRD system
concedes that, for each
chunk of natural resources,
there ought to be just one
agent in control. We do not
want everybody to own a
share in every bit of the
globe; that would be far too
complicated and unwieldy.
Yet, we also cannot endorse
a system, such as we have
now, where many people
cannot get even a remotely
proportional share of the
natural resources humanity
is extracting from this
planet. Nor can we accept
that contingencies, such as
the scarcity or abundance of
water or oil in some
particular territory, say,
have an excessively large
impact on the fate of its
inhabitants. The GRD might
then be a reasonable
compromise: each society has
full control of the
resources within its
territory, but, when it
decides to make use of any
of these resources, then it
must share a small part of
the value of these resources
with the rest of humankind
and specifically with the
global poor who would
otherwise get much less than
a fair share of our planet’s
resource wealth. This is the
basic idea of the GRD. It is
just a different way of
conceiving property rights
from the standard way. We
have to be careful, however,
to avoid misunderstanding
this idea. In the twentieth
century, the developing
countries fought hard to win
full sovereignty over the
resources in their
territory. This was an
important struggle, and I do
not want anyone to think
that I seek to have its
outcome reversed. My
proposal is merely that poor
and rich countries alike
share a small portion of the
value of any national
resources they choose to use
while retaining full control
over the decision whether
and how to use their
national resources. It is
also worth emphasizing, in
addition, that most of the
cost of this GRD would
ultimately fall upon the
end-users of natural
resources, as most of the
required dividend payments
would be passed along
through higher prices. The
richer people are the ones
with higher consumption, so
they would be
disproportionately affected
by an increase in the price
of resource-intensive kinds
of consumption (such as air
travel). Poorer people would
be net beneficiaries, as the
revenues from the GRD would
be spent for their benefit.
And all people, including
future generations, would
benefit from the
disincentive (through higher
prices) against
resource-intensive
consumption.
Duarte: Are you
suggesting that there should
be a difference between land
ownership and land
management in the case of
the nation states? Pogge: There is
certainly a difference. The
GRD does not take away any
of the management rights
from countries. The
management rights or the
right to control the natural
resources available within
their territory would
definitely stay with the
countries, and in this sense
the historical victory of
the developing countries in
their struggle to free
themselves from colonialism
would remain intact.
To clarify the distinction,
imagine, for example, that
there is a large amount of
oil situated under a holy
site of a certain country.
If the people in this
country decide not to
extract the oil in order not
to disturb the holy site,
their decision should be
respected. These people
should not even be charged,
in my view, for the
privilege of blocking access
to this resource, because
any such charge might put
undue pressure on them to
reluctantly permit its
extraction. If these people
decide, however, to extract
the resource for their own
benefit, then they would on
my proposal be required to
share some small fraction of
the market value of the
extracted resource on the
principle that the Earth
belongs to all human beings
in common and that it would
be wrong to exclude—as is
the current practice—the
world’s poor from their fair
share of our planet’s
natural wealth.
In the present system, rich
people monopolize the
natural resources of our
planet. Rich people in one
country claim ownership over
its natural resources and
then sell them to other
affluent people often
residing in other countries.
All this happens by mutual
consent with nice mutually
agreeable contracts under
which the resources are
processed and finally
consumed by affluent people.
The world’s poor—and this
easily includes the entire
poorer half of humanity
which currently receives
only three per cent of
global household
income—cannot get access to
more than a tiny fraction of
a proportional share of the
natural resources extracted,
and this is, in my view,
very unfair.
Duarte: It is
certainly unfair. With a
global resources dividend
system the poor would be
much less vulnerable to
exploitation. Brazil is a
country very rich in natural
resources, but the resources
are still controlled by
elites. By distributing
these resources to the whole
population, Brazil would
certainly improve
considerably in terms of
development, right?
Pogge: Yes,
this would surely be a huge
boost to development. It
would allow poor people to
partake in the resource
wealth of the country, which
should not benefit merely a
few rich owners, but all
Brazilians. Everyone should
partake in natural resource
wealth because no one has a
prior or superior claim to
any of these resources. We
have a collective
responsibility to regulate
the exploitation of natural
resources in such a way that
no one is excluded from a
fair share. This means, in
particular, that no one
should be allowed to benefit
from a much larger than
average share without
compensating those who are
reduced to much smaller than
average shares.
IV. Global
Institutions
and the Combat
of Poverty in
Brazil
Duarte:
What is, in
your opinion,
the role of
global
institutions
in the
increase/decrease
of poverty in
Brazil in the
last decade?
Do you think
that this role
will change
from now on,
since the
Brazilian
Roberto
Azevedo has
been selected
to be the next
director of
the World
Trade
Organization
(WTO)?
Pogge:
The role
of the global
institutions
with regard to
poverty in
Brazil will
probably not
change
significantly.
This is
because
decisions by
the World
Trade
Organization
are made by
consensus,
which is
driven by the
very unequal
bargaining
power of the
member states.
With their
enormous
economic and
military
might, Western
countries will
remain the
dominant
powers in the
WTO, even if a
Brazilian
becomes the
body’s
director. Of
course, Brazil
is a rising
power. It is
the
seventh-largest
economy in the
world and,
given its size
and resources,
has a very
realistic
opportunity to
overtake the
United
Kingdom,
France,
Germany and
Japan in the
near future.
Brazil’s
influence is
increasing
also because
it has
intelligently
aligned itself
within the
IBSA
countries:
India and
South Africa.
They have
formed a
powerful
partnership of
rapidly
growing
countries,
which now have
substantial
influence in
and through
the G20. This
will
increasingly
help Brazil to
develop, to
achieve solid
rates of
economic
growth and to
protect its
interests. It
is true that
Brazil was
badly treated
in earlier
decades,
severely
exploited by
multinational
banks and
corporations
backed by the
United States,
which also
supported and
collaborated
with the
military
dictatorship
from 1964 to
1985. These
were unhappy
times for
Brazil in many
ways,
politically
and
economically.
Nevertheless,
Brazil has now
emerged as a
country that
has largely
emancipated
itself from
this sort of
foreign
pressure and
domination.
Brazil cannot
be pushed
around any
more, like it
was pushed
around twenty,
thirty years
ago, and this
certainly
bodes well for
progress,
prosperity and
development.
The great
danger now,
however, is
that both
national and
supranational
institutional
arrangements
will benefit
some
Brazilians at
the expense of
the great
majority of
their
compatriots.
Such
arrangements
might be
shaped to
aggravate
existing
social and
economic
inequalities,
which in
Brazil are
already
enormous. This
is something
we have
witnessed all
over the world
during the
last 30 years
or so:
globalization
has led to
socio-economic
polarization
in most
countries
including,
rather
dramatically,
China and the
United States.
In recent
years, Brazil
has managed to
escape this
trend. Through
policies
initiated by
Lula,10Brazil
has actually
reduced
inequality
over the last
ten years. But
to put this in
perspective, I
should add
that when Lula
was elected,
inequality in
Brazil was
among the very
highest in the
world and it
is still very
high in
comparison to
inequality in
other
countries,
especially
outside Latin
America and
Southern
Africa.
Inequality in
Brazil is
deeply
entrenched and
therefore hard
to dislodge:
it is strongly
correlated
with race and
transmitted
from one
generation to
the next by
means of a
highly unequal
education
system. Still,
overall I am
cautiously
optimistic
that progress
can continue
with
democratic
support from a
majority of
Brazil’s
citizens.
Progress on
the inequality
front will
have to be
achieved
against the
influence
exerted by
global
institutional
arrangements,
which
generally
favour greater
inequality.
This is hardly
surprising.
These global
institutional
arrangements
have rapidly
become much
denser and
more
influential
during the
globalization
push of the
last 30 years.
These new
global rules
(such as those
of the WTO),
which now
reach deep
into the inner
lives of
national
societies,
were shaped by
the
governments of
the leading
developed
states, and
these
governments in
turn were
heavily
influenced by
the interests
of their most
powerful
constituents:
multinational
corporations,
large banks,
industry
associations,
hedge funds
and
billionaires.
As a result,
globalization
is benefitting
the rich at
the expense of
the poor in
many different
ways. This is
not a fact
about
globalization
as such, but a
fact about
this
globalization:
globalization
under the
specific rules
and agencies
that have
emerged or
been
strengthened
over the last
30 years or
so.
One could give
many examples;
here are four:
the permitted
protectionism
the rich
countries
managed to get
“grandfathered”
into the WTO
Agreement to
protect, in
particular,
their domestic
agriculture at
the expense of
farmers in the
poor
countries; the
very strong
intellectual
property rules
the rich
countries
imposed upon
the rest
through the
TRIPs
Agreement
(Trade-Related
Aspects of
Intellectual
Property
Rights) (Annex
1C of the WTO
Agreement); an
international
tax system
that in effect
enables
multinational
corporations
to shift their
profits into
tax havens and
thus to avoid
paying taxes
in the
developing
countries
where their
profits
originate; and
the
facilitation
of large,
quick and
secret
movements of
capital across
national
borders, which
supports tax
evasion,
embezzlement,
money
laundering,
human and drug
trafficking,
terrorism as
well as other
forms of crime
especially in
the developing
world. These
rules affect
Brazil and
harm, in
particular,
its poor:
sharecroppers,
patients and
those who
depend on the
society’s
social safety
net. These
same rules
also benefit
some rich
Brazilians who
can, for
example, keep
their wealth
in secrecy
jurisdictions
abroad and
thus avoid
paying taxes
on their
earnings from
capital. This
is actually
quite common.
The Boston
Consulting
Group
estimates that
Latin
Americans keep
an
unimaginable
US $1 trillion
abroad; that
is 25.6 per
cent of their
collective
financial
wealth, while
the analogous
estimates for
North America
and Europe are
1.8 per cent
and 7.9 per
cent,
respectively.11
Obviously,
when poor
countries are
unable to tax
capital
income, they
must cut back
government
services or
get more of
their revenues
from taxes on
labour income
and from
consumption
taxes, which
place greater
burdens on the
poor.
Now
it should also
be said that
the Brazilian
government has
taken
intelligent
steps to
improve its
tax collection
from rich
individuals
and especially
from
multinational
corporations.
Brazil has a
comparatively
well-run tax
system that
works better
than those in
other Latin
American
countries and
much better
than those in
Africa. Still,
Brazil would
benefit from
international
reforms that
would increase
financial
transparency
at both the
domestic and
global levels
in order to
curb tax
avoidance and
evasion. Among
the most
important
reforms,
governments
should
mandate: (1)
disclosure of
the ultimate
beneficial
owners of
companies and
of the
controlling
parties of
trusts and
foundations;
(2) public
country-by-country
reporting of
profits and
other
tax-relevant
information by
multinational
enterprises;
(3) automatic
exchange of
tax-relevant
financial
information by
national tax
authorities
worldwide; (4)
public
reporting on
funds paid to
governments
for the
extraction of
natural
resources and
on the use of
those funds;
and (5) tough
sanctions,
including jail
time, for
professionals
who facilitate
illicit
financial
flows, for
instance
senior
officers from
global banks,
accounting
firms, law
firms,
insurance
companies and
hedge funds.
In addition,
governments
should commit
to: (6)
harmonizing
anti-money
laundering
regulations
internationally;
and (7)
carrying out
clear,
reliable,
frequent and
timely public
fiscal
reporting as
well as
opening up
their fiscal
policy-making
process to
public
participation.12
Such reforms
would promote
greater
domestic
resource
mobilization
in Brazil and
especially
also in other,
poorer
developing
countries.
V. National Partiality and Impartiality in
Government Decisions
Duarte: For
a long time, Brazil was a debtor
of the International Monetary
Fund (IMF). However, the
situation has changed and from
debtor it became creditor of
IMF. Brazil is lending US $10
billion to the organization in
order to help bail European
countries out of their current
crisis.13
Such government decisions can,
perhaps, be seen as “impartial”
from a national standpoint
since, besides reducing the high
rates of poverty within the
country, the money is going to
be used to help richer
countries—which until now have
benefited from the Brazilian
debt with IMF. In your book
(Pogge 2010: 23-4), you said
that “partiality of concern is
alright within a minimally fair
setting, but not all right when
it seeks to undermine the
minimal fairness of this setting
itself.” So, my question is:
Does impartiality of concern
have this minimal fair setting
as well? And if it does, do you
think that Brazil is overlooking
these limits when lending money
to the IMF?
Pogge:
The system
that we have
at the moment
is certainly
not a fair
system that
takes equally
into account
the interests
of rich and
poor people.
For this
reason, even
when not
privileging
its citizens,
the government
is not totally
impartial. The
system we live
under is
designed by
the rich for
the rich.
Certainly, the
system is in
the first
instance
designed by
nation states,
by governments
and by their
delegated
negotiators
who sit
together to
decide what
the rules of
the game
should be, in
the context of
the G20, for
example. These
governments
are, however,
influenced by
their most
powerful
constituents—by
big national
industry
associations,
multinational
corporations,
banks, hedge
funds,
billionaires—and
unfortunately,
the Brazilian
government is
no exception.
Government
policies,
especially
foreign
policies and
negotiating
positions in
international
negotiations,
are very
heavily
moulded by a
country’s most
powerful
constituents,
and
governments
pay far more
attention to
these powerful
constituents
than to the
poorer
majority of
the country
who often lack
the time and
education to
form opinions
on these
matters. As a
result, the
supranational
rules of the
game, for
example those
structuring
the world
economy, are
certainly not
impartial,
certainly not
based on the
equally
weighted
interests of
all
participants. Now,
your question
is whether it
is all right
for Brazil to
help overcome
the financial
crisis in
Europe, to
give some
money to the
IMF for the
purposes of
assisting the
Europeans.
Now, this is
not money
given as a
donation; it
is rather a
loan given to
the Europeans
to shore up
their
financial
system. You
might say this
is part of a
cooperative
system, a
special sort
of insurance
scheme where,
in case any
country falls
upon hard
times, it can
count on the
assistance of
others,
through loans,
not through
gifts. So it’s
a bit like a
scheme of fire
insurance: if
someone’s
house catches
fire, then one
gets financial
assistance for
rebuilding,
assistance
that is funded
from the
insurance
premium of
many other
homeowners.
But there is
still this
difference,
that
homeowners get
the rebuilding
money as a
grant whereas
countries get
IMF funds as a
loan that must
eventually be
paid back.
In principle,
such an
insurance
scheme is
valuable
because the
overall
financial
system is an
important part
of the
infrastructure
that makes the
whole global
economic
system
function. The
North Atlantic
financial
crisis of 2008
was, and still
is, a danger
to the whole
world.
Fortunately,
the crisis was
reasonably
contained
before
producing more
damage around
the world. It
strongly
affected the
United States
and Europe,
but it did not
really affect
Brazil and
most other
less-developed
countries. It
affected China
because China
is a major
exporter to
the United
States and the
European
Union. Brazil
was less
affected
because the
principal
destination of
its exports is
China. In any
case, any
national
economy today
depends on the
health of the
global
financial
system, and it
is therefore
in each
country’s
interest to
contribute to
a fair and
effective
scheme for
stabilizing
the world
financial
system through
mutual
lending.
Apart from the
nice symbolic
significance
of Brazil’s
contributing
US $10 billion
(along with
other less
developed
countries) to
this bailout
of Europe,
Brazil
benefits from
its loan
insofar as it
will be able
to call upon
similar
support in
case of
domestic
financial
difficulties
and also
insofar as its
economic
position
benefits from
a deeper and
more severe
crisis being
averted in
Europe and in
the United
States. To be
sure, we must
always
remember that
the present
global
financial
system is not
a fair or just
system. It is
a system
skewed in
favour of the
rich. Still, a
deepening of
the North
Atlantic
crisis would
have had an
adverse impact
on Brazil and
its citizens.
Although some
clever rich
people in
Europe and in
North America
were able to
make a lot of
money on the
crisis, this
was a tiny
minority. The
vast majority,
rich and poor
alike, were
hurt by the
crisis. And
because the
harm was so
widespread, it
was genuinely
important, I
think, to
contain this
harm, to make
sure that the
crisis did not
become deeper
and did not
spread into
the far more
vulnerable
poor
countries.
Given all
this, it was
the right
policy
decision to
participate in
loans to
Europe to help
bail out the
countries most
affected by
the crises.
VI. Owl of Minerva Spreading
its Wings before the Falling
of Dusk
Duarte:
According to
you, for the
first time the
owl of Minerva
is finally
“spreading its
wings well
before the
falling of
dusk,” and
this means
that
philosophy has
actually “been
giving an
important
conceptual
impulse to
economics,
political
science, and
politics” (Pogge
2010: 25).
Will
philosophy
influence the
agenda
post-2015
after the
first UN
Millennium
Development
Goals (MDGs)?
What measures
could be taken
to limit the
possibilities
of moving the
goal posts and
of ensuring
that poverty
is finally
defeated?
Pogge:
We are
certainly
living in a
very important
time in
history. It is
a time in
which the
global
institutional
architecture
is being
shaped and in
which
philosophy can
potentially
provide
important
normative
input. We also
had such a
period of
globalization
and
institutional
reshaping in
the late
nineteenth to
early
twentieth
century, but
it came to an
abrupt and
tragic halt
with the First
World War. It
started up a
little bit
again in the
1920s, but
then came the
even more
horrendous
Second World
War, of
course. Now we
are making the
third attempt
towards a more
cosmopolitan
order, and
this time it
looks like
such an order
will be
established
and become
irreversible.
We are
building a new
global
institutional
infrastructure,
and the rules
of this
infrastructure
are now in the
process of
being shaped.
To build and
understand
this
infrastructure,
new concepts
and theories
are necessary:
in law, in
political
science, in
economics and
also in
philosophy.
The
emergence of a
dense and
highly
influential
global
institutional
order can be
compared to
the building
of a city,
such as New
York, for
example. New
York changes
all the time,
as people,
companies and
industries
come and go,
as buildings
get torn down
and erected,
as
transportation
and
communication
systems get
modernized.
And yet, the
basic features
of the city
stay much the
same, even
over
centuries: the
grid of
streets, the
location of
the parks,
subway lines,
bridges and
tunnels, and
so on. These
basic features
have
tremendous
inertia; they
could be
altered, but
it would be
extremely
difficult to
do so—not only
because of the
enormous
expense
involved but
also because
of the vested
interests that
have formed
around these
features.
Early
decisions
about the
basic features
of the city
thus turned
out to have a
profound
influence
lasting for
centuries. It
is similar, I
think, with
the early
decisions that
are now being
made about the
emerging
global
institutional
infrastructure.
These basic
features, too,
will be deeply
entrenched by
the complexity
and expense of
altering them
as well as by
the vested
interests that
are forming
around them.
More than most
other
generations in
human history,
we are
profoundly
shaping the
future of
humanity, not
just for the
next few
decades, but
for centuries
and (if
humanity is so
lucky!)
millennia to
come.
This
rapid
emergence of a
critically
important
global
institutional
infrastructure
has been going
on for 30
years. And it
has in many
ways been
badly
designed,
morally
speaking, in
blatant
disregard of
the needs and
interests of
the poorer
majority of
humankind. My
generation
bears a grave
responsibility
in this
regard. The
more
progressive
people of my
generation—those
who are
concerned
about severe
poverty and
excessive
inequality,
those who care
about human
rights and
about genuine
political
participation
for all—have,
by and large,
missed these
developments.
The global
corporate
elites, the
leaders of
business and
finance, on
the other
hand, were
highly alert.
Overcoming
many
differences
among
themselves,
they have
managed to
bring enormous
influence to
bear on the
most powerful
politicians
and have
essentially
succeeded in
shaping the
new global
institutional
infrastructure
according to
their shared
interests. To
be sure, these
elites bear no
ill will
against the
poorer
majority, not
at all. They
merely give
priority to
their own
interests.
Their great
influence thus
results in
global
institutional
arrangements
that secure
them a large
and
ever-increasing
share of
global income,
which of
necessity is
associated
with rising
global
inequality and
with the
persistence of
severe poverty
as the poorer
half of
humankind has
been reduced
to barely 3
per cent of
global
household
income.
Regulatory
capture—politicians and regulators coming under the
influence of wealthy elites who then dominate the
formulation and application of rules—has destructive
effects not only on the poor. It also leads to
regulatory incoherence and to the neglect of the
future. Regulatory incoherence occurs because elite
players differ with regard to which rules and
regulations will affect them the most. This is where
each will concentrate its lobbying efforts. As a
result, different parts of the emerging supranational
institutional infrastructure are shaped by different
interest groups rather than designed for optimal
coherence and effectiveness with regard to some chosen
purpose. Neglect of the future occurs because elite
players are focused on the short term. The CEOs of
powerful banks or corporations typically have just a
few years until retirement and, during this time,
their retention and pay are massively dependent on
their performance relative to that of their peers at
competing enterprises. The long-term health of the
world’s economy and ecology has no impact on their
bonuses and stock options. Hedge fund managers and
most large investors are even more clearly focused on
the near term. They can quickly switch investments and
even “go short” and thereby avoid, or even profit
from, any long-term adverse effects of their decisions
and lobbying efforts. Regulatory capture magnifies
these pathologies insofar as enterprise leaders’
myopic appetite for short-term profits comes to
dominate not merely the operations of their respective
enterprises but also the policies and
institutional-design preferences of their state. Just
think about it: the United States is involved in
international negotiations whose outcome will shape
important aspects of the world economy for centuries,
and the US position is formulated by a bunch of
powerful enterprise leaders focused on the vast sums
they can earn if their respective enterprises make
extraordinary profits in the next few years.
Obviously, we
need a far
more
thoughtful and
democratic way
of building
the
infrastructure
of our
increasingly
interdependent
world. We
would be
better off if
we could think
more
holistically
and
universalistically
about the kind
of cosmopolis
we want to
build—about
the basic
features of a
political and
economic order
that could
last for
centuries. It
is in this
regard that
the owl of
Minerva must
spread its
wings before
the falling of
dusk:
Philosophy
can, and
should, and is
beginning to,
play a more
constructive
role in
shaping and
revising the
emerging
global
infrastructure
with an eye to
humanity’s
long-term
future. Given
that our
institutional
design
decisions in
this crucial
phase of human
history will
profoundly
affect the
future, we
have a
responsibility
to make these
decisions with
all the
foresight we
can reasonably
summon. We
have to think
seriously and
with the best
academic
inputs about
how a future
fully
globalized
world should
best be
governed, how
its economic
system should
work, how its
financial
system should
be designed.
How can we
envision, a
century in the
future, a
world order
that ensures
safety,
freedom and
prosperity for
all human
beings and is
politically
reachable from
where we are?
If we don’t
face this
question
systematically,
if we just
muddle through
as directed by
the momentary
agreements
among
short-term
orientated
political and
economic
elites, then
humanity is
highly
unlikely to
attain such a
morally
liveable
world. In
fact, we may
fail our very
first serious
test as a
species: The
challenge of
anthropogenic
climate
change. About
the
development
goals
post-2015, in
my lecture at
the conference
on Realizing
Global
Justice:
Theory and
Practice at
the UiT The
Arctic
University of
Norway,14I
gave a summary
of what I
think would be
goals of the
right kind.
They differ
from the goals
that are
standardly
discussed,
such as the
MDGs and also
their
successors,
the
“Sustainable
Development
Goals”,
drafted by a
high-level
panel of
eminent
persons.15The
goals I
advocate
differ in that
they commit
states not
merely to the
proposition
that some
outcomes ought
to happen, but
to concrete
changes in the
existing
institutional
arrangements
that would
actually lead
to these
outcomes. It
is easy to
endorse a list
of pious
wishes: less
poverty, more
female
education,
less
corruption,
better health
care. But
these good
things are not
going to
happen just
because a lot
of states
agree that
they should.
What we need
is agreement
on who is
supposed to do
what to bring
about these
good things.
For example,
to reduce
poverty in the
less developed
countries, we
need to stop
their being
drained of
capital and
tax revenues
by their own
economic and
political
elites and by
the accounting
gimmicks of
multinational
enterprises.
We need to
dismantle the
financial-secrecy
infrastructure
of tax havens,
shell
companies,
secrecy
jurisdictions
and anonymous
trusts with
their sleazy
banks, lawyers
and
accountants.
Concerted
action by the
affluent
states could
easily achieve
a massive
reduction in
illicit
financial
flows. And,
driven by
post-crisis
public anger
in these
countries,
there is
actually a
great deal of
movement now
in this
direction, in
the OECD and
the G20, most
visibly. This
is a great
opportunity to
achieve the
necessary
reforms of the
international
financial
system. Here
it is crucial
that the
reforms fully
include the
needs and
interests of
the less
developed
countries,
which suffer
vastly more
from this
problem than
affluent
countries do.
So what goals
or targets
might
countries
agree upon to
really tackle
this problem?
Well, for
example the
seven reforms
I mentioned
earlier.
Duarte: You, Sen, and others have
heavily criticized the way poverty has been measured
(Pogge 2010, 57-74). Could you quickly update us
with your final findings on the development of a
holistic way of measuring poverty (Pogge 2010,
75-92)?
Pogge:
In May 2013 we
had the final
conference in
Oslo where we
presented the
results of our
research
project
Measuring
Poverty and
Gender
Disparity.16This was a three-year project of participatory
research where we talked with poor people in 18
different sites—one urban, one rural and one
marginalized community in each of Angola, Fiji,
Indonesia, Malawi, Mozambique, and the Philippines—in
order to understand what they think poverty is all
about. Our work consisted of three phases. The first
phase featured unstructured conversations exploring
what constitutes poverty, what the different levels
and dimensions of poverty are and how sex and age
affect the reality and experience of poverty. From
this phase, 25 dimensions of poverty emerged, and we
used these as the basis for our more structured
interviews in the second phase. On the basis of these
interviews, we reduced our measure to 15 important
dimensions, distinguishing five levels in each. We
also assigned different weights to the dimensions and
to the intervals between levels in each dimension; the
lowest interval in the most important dimensions
received 12 times as much weight as the highest
interval in the least important dimensions.
Accommodating the reflections of poor people
themselves, we ended up with a measure of poverty that
is multidimensional, gender-sensitive in its choice of
dimensions and also individualistic by assessing the
deprivations and hardships of each person (when nearly
all other measures of poverty base the poverty status
of persons on the condition of the household they
belong to). In the third phase, which we had funds to
run only in the Philippines, we actually used the
poverty measure we had developed for a survey of a
random sample of some 1800 people in order to learn
how poor people do by the light of our metric and
whether this metric offers an appropriate way of
measuring poverty and gender disparities. Here we
found one very surprising thing: poor women are
slightly better off than poor men in the Philippines.
Duarte: Is this because women would
better administer their incomes?
Pogge:
This could
well be part
of the
explanation.
But in many
cases the
women and men
live together
in the same
household, and
so women’s
more
responsible
money
management
should benefit
both. Of
course, the
surprising
result could
be a fluke
since the
difference we
found, albeit
statistically
significant,
was small. But
the fact
remains that
we did not
find what we
expected to
find: a clear
advantage for
males. I am
sure we would
have found
such a male
advantage in
most other
countries.
Perhaps our
result would
not hold up
statistically
if one were to
conduct a
larger survey
or if our
survey had not
missed a
number of
absent males.
In any case,
the result is
not a huge
embarrassment
for our work
insofar as
much other
fieldwork
confirms that
the
Philippines is
doing
relatively
well in terms
of gender
disparities.
According to
the 2013
Global Gender
Gap Report,17the Philippines is among the top countries in
terms of gender equality, number five in the 2013
world ranking. This is not true of Brazil, I am sure.
Duarte: No, unfortunately it is not.
Even with a female president, I am afraid to say
that Brazil is number sixty-two in the world
ranking, way behind the Philippines.
Pogge: I
understand,
and this is
why it is so
important to
get funding to
continue with
this project.
We hope that
in the near
future we will
get funding to
implement our
phase-three
survey in
other
countries,
such as Fiji,
for
example.
Duarte:
What were the
questions you
used to build
up your data?18
Pogge: In different phases we worked with
different questions. In the first phase, we started
with very open questions, such as: are there different
levels of poverty? There are certainly
differentiations among the poor, but can one measure
these differences? How do we recognize whether a
person is poor or extremely poor? We received diverse
answers in different countries. In some places,
different levels of poverty are recognized by looking
at how people sleep: some people sleep on the ground,
some people sleep on a kind of mattress. In other
countries, differentiations are based on how people
are dressed, and so forth. We found more and more of
this information and worked it into a schema of levels
and dimensions: there are people who are poor, not so
poor, and extremely poor. We found that some of the
dimensions that poor people stress as important are,
superficially at least, quite remote from what in
ordinary affluent circles would be considered a marker
of poverty. A very important part of the experience of
being poor, for example, is vulnerability to violence.
Being poor means being exposed to violence. Poor
people typically do not have a house or apartment
where they can just lock the door behind them and be
safe. They may be homeless, perhaps living on the
street or in some shelter that others can invade at
any time. Very poor people also receive very little
protection from the court system or from the police—in
fact, violence against the poor is often perpetrated
by the police! Poor people are endlessly abused,
kicked around, mistreated—with impunity—by their
“social betters” by supervisors or employers, by
officials and by anyone who feels like it. The
prominence poor people give to the experience of
violence surprised us, but if this is what poor people
say is an important part of poverty, then it is, and
we have to pay attention to it, right?
Duarte:
What about
happiness? Is
happiness on
your list?
Pogge: No, we did not ask people about their
subjective level of satisfaction or happiness.
Duarte:
Is this
because
happiness is
very difficult
to measure?
Pogge:
Yes,
partly. But
the
fundamental
problem is
that a focus
on happiness
brings in
normatively
inappropriate
factors
including, in
particular, a
person’s
ambitions and
expectations.
Somebody who
is raised to
expect very
little is well
adapted to her
lack of means
and may well
be content
with a meagre,
monotonous
diet and
primitive
living
conditions.
Still, by
raising people
in this way,
we are not
overcoming
poverty but,
if anything,
entrenching
poverty by
ensuring that
people are
well adapted
to it. Think
also of the
parallel case
of gender
disparity. A
country has
not overcome
gender
disparity when
its females
are as happy
with their
subservient
role as its
males are with
their much
greater
opportunities.
This is not
merely a
conceptual
point but a
moral one: we
ought to
achieve a
nutritious and
diversified
diet, hygienic
and private
sanitation,
clean water,
and so on,
even for
people whose
extreme
poverty has
placed such
achievements
beyond their
imagination.
And we ought
to achieve
equal
opportunities
even for those
girls and
women whose
life-long
subordination
has thwarted
even the
development of
any such
ambition. In
this special
case, where
poor people’s
ambitions are
stunted by
their
circumstances,
it would be
inappropriate
to use the
former to
validate the
latter. This
is not
tantamount to
asking
policymakers
to re-educate
such people or
to force them
to accept the
amenities of
modern life.
But, if they
are serious
about
overcoming
poverty, then
policymakers
should provide
opportunities
for a life
free from
deprivation,
and these
opportunities
will then help
ensure that
the next
generation, at
least, will
develop higher
ambitions in
terms of food,
sanitation,
shelter,
education,
health care,
and absence of
gender-based
constraints.
To be sure,
with such
higher
ambitions
comes loss of
the capacity
to be content
with serious
deprivations
or with
gender-based
subservience.
Endorsing this
trade-off is a
moral choice
and, I think,
the right
moral
choice—though
I realize this
is a large
subject about
which a lot
more could be
said.
Notes
1 Melina Duarte, PhD, is a
Researcher in
Political
Philosophy at
UiT The Arctic
University of
Norway. For
more
interviews,
see: Duarte,
M., Jakobsen
& J.,
Dege, C.
(2013:
171-183). She
is most
thankful to
the Justice
and
Development
Research
Group, Federal
University of
Rio Grande do
Sul, in
Brazil, for
valuable
discussions on
the topics of
this
interview.
Contact:
melina.duarte@uit.no.
The interview
was held on 23
June, 2013, at
UiT The Arctic
University of
Norway, on the
occasion of
the
international
conference on
Realizing
Global
Justice:
Theory and
Practice. This
interview is
part of a
series of
interviews
with the
keynote
speakers. The
conference and
the interview
series were
organized by
the Pluralism,
Democracy, and
Justice
Research Group
funded by the
Justice in
Conflict
Project
(2010-2015),
Research
Council of
Norway, in
collaboration
with the
Brazilian
magazine
Filosofia
Ciência &
Vida, edited
by Paula Palma
Félix. 2Find
the paper at
http://www.law.yale.edu/documents/pdf/
LawJournals/1._Pogge.pdf. 3See
more about
Thomas Pogge
at
http://pantheon.yale.edu/~tp4/. 4See
links to
Pogge’s TED
talk about
this topic and
more
information at
http://www.ted.com/talk/thomas_pogge_medicine_for_
the_99_percent.html
and
www.healthimpactfund.org.
See also:
Aidan
Hollis and
Thomas Pogge,
The
Health Impact
Fund: Making
New
Medicines
Accessible for
All. Oslo
and New Haven,
Incentives for
Global Health,
2008; Thomas
Pogge, World
Poverty and
Human Rights:
Cosmopolitan
Responsibilities
and Reforms,
2nd
edition
(Cambridge and
Malden: Polity
Press 2008),
222–61. 5See
Thomas Pogge,
World
Poverty and
Human Rights,
ibid., pp.
202–21. See
also
translation to
Portuguese: O
Fundo de
impactosobre a saúde e sua justificativa pelo apelo
aos Direitos
Humanos, trans. Pascoal Teófilo Carvalho Gonçalves, inIdéias,
Journal of the
Institute of
Philosophy and
Social
Sciences,
Unicamp, no. 6
(2013):
99–147,
www.ifch.unicamp.br/ojs/index.php/ideias/article/view/1395/969. 6Thomas
Pogge,Politics
as Usual: What
Lies behind
the Pro-Poor
Rhetoric
(Cambridge and
Malden: Polity
Press 2010),
75–92; Thomas
Pogge and
Nicole Rippin,
Universal
Agenda on the
Multiple
Dimensions of
Poverty,
background
research paper
submitted to
the High Level
Panel
on the
Post-2015
Development
Agenda, May
2013,
www.post2015hlp.org/wp-content/uploads/2013/05/Pogge-
Rippin_Universal-Agenda-on-the-Multiple-Dimensions-of-Poverty.pdf.
See
also
www.genderpovertymeasure.org/. 7See
Tax
Abuses,
Poverty and
Human Rights,
produced by
the
International
Bar
Association’s
Human Rights
Institute
(IBAHRI) Task
Force on
Illicit
Financial
Flows, Poverty
and Human
Rights,
chaired by
Thomas Pogge
(London:
International
Bar
Association
2013),
www.ibanet.org/Article/Detail.aspx?ArticleUid=4A0CF930-
A0D1-4784-8D09-F588DCDDFEA4. 8See
more
information at
http://www2.planalto.gov.br/especiais
/caderno-destaques/marco-2013/gestao-em-destaque/erradicacao-
da-extrema-pobreza. 9See
more about the
benefits of
the program at
http://go.worldbank.org
/3QI1C7B5U0. 10LuizInácio
Lula da Silva,
President of
Brazil from
2003 to 2011.
In 2011, his
successor, the
current
President
Dilma
Rousseff, was
elected. 11Boston Consulting Group, “Global Wealth 2013:
Maintaining
Momentum in a
Complex
World,”4
and 11,
available at www.bcg.de/documents/file135355.pdf.
Africa and the
Middle East
are doing even
worse than
Latin America:
fully one
third of their
collective
financial
wealth is held
abroad, about
1.6 trillion
US-dollars. 12
These were
among the
leading
demands that
emerged from a
crowd-
funded Delphi
study
(http://academicsstand.org/2014/05/asap-study- curbing-illicit-financial-flows-post-2015)
that ASAP
completed with
a panel of 29
leading
experts. 13See:
http://en.mercopress.com/2009/10/05/historic-day-for-brazil- which-for-the-first-time-becomes-imf-creditor. 14Watch
the full
lecture at
http://mediasite.uit.no/Mediasite/Catalog
/Full/11629ab59d35420d8ab50d3ae1263be621. 15For
the former,
see The
Millennium
Development
Goals Report
2014 (New
York City,
United Nations
2014),
www.un.org/millenniumgoals
/2014%20MDG%20report/MDG%202014%20English%20web.pdf.
For
the latter,
see the
current draft
at
http://sustainabledevelopment.un.org
/focussdgs.html. 16For first results on this research, see Thomas Pogge
and Nicole
Rippin,
“Universal
Agenda on the
Multiple
Dimensions of
Poverty”,
background
research paper
submitted to
the High Level
Panel on the
Post-2015
Development
Agenda, May
2013,
www.post2015hlp.org/wp-
content/uploads/2013/05/Pogge-Rippin_Universal-Agenda-on-the-
Multiple-Dimensions-of-Poverty.pdf;
and
http://www.genderpovertymeasure.org/. 17See
2013 Report at
http://www3.weforum.org/docs/WEF_GenderGap_Report_2013.pdf. 18
Questionnaires
and final
report are now
available at
http://www.genderpovertymeasure.org/publications/.
References
Duarte, M.,
Jakobsen &
J., Dege, C.
(2013).
Reassessing
Human Rights:
An Interview
with Seyla
Benhabib. Norsk
filosofisk
tidskrift
48 (2):
171–183.
Pogge, T.
(2008). World
Poverty and
Human Rights:
Cosmopolitan
Responsibilities
and Reforms,
2nd ed.
Cambridge and
Malden, Polity
Press.
Pogge,
T. &
Hollis, A.
(2008). The
Health Impact
Fund: Making
New Medicines
Accessible for
All. Oslo
and New Haven,
Incentives for
Global Health.
Pogge. T.
(2010). Politics
as Usual: What
Lies Behind
the Pro-Poor
Rhetoric.
Cambridge and
Malden: Polity
Press.
Pogge. T.
(2011) “Are We
Violating the
Human Rights
of the World’s
Poor?” Yale
Human Rights
&
Development
Law Journal
14, no. 2:
1–33. Winner
of the 2013
Gregory Kavka
Prize in
political
philosophy
administered
by the
American
Philosophical
Association.
Available at
http://www.law.yale.edu/documents/pdf/LawJournals/1._Pogge.pdf
Pogge
T. & and
Horton, K.
(eds). (2008).
Global Ethics:
Seminal
Essays. St.
Paul, Paragon
House.
Pogge, T.
(2013a) “O
Fundo de
impacto sobre
a saúde e sua
justificativa
pelo apelo aos
Direitos
Humanos,”
translated by
Pascoal
Teófilo
Carvalho
Gonçalves,
Idéias -
Revista do
Instituto de
Filosofia e
Ciências
Humanas -
Unicamp n. 6:
99–147.
Available at
http://www.ifch.unicamp.br/ojs/index.php/ideias/article/view/1395/969.
Pogge, T.
(2013b). Tax
Abuses,
Poverty and
Human Rights.
Produced by
the
International
Bar
Association’s
Human Rights
Institute
(IBAHRI) Task
Force on
Illicit
Financial
Flows, Poverty
and Human
Rights,
chaired by
Thomas Pogge.
London:
International
Bar
Association.
Available at
http://www.ibanet.org/Article/Detail.aspx?
ArticleUid=4A0CF930-A0D1-4784-8D09-F588DCDDFEA4.
Pogge, T.
& Rippin
N. (2013c).
Universal
Agenda on the
Multiple
Dimensions of
Poverty.
Background
research paper
submitted to
the High Level
Panel on the
Post-2015
Development
Agenda, May.
Available at
http://www.post2015hlp.org/wp-content/uploads
/2013/05/Pogge-Rippin_Universal-Agenda-on-the-Multiple-
Dimensions-of-Poverty.pdf.
Pogge, T.
& Sengupta
M. (2014).
Rethinking the
Post-2015
Development
Agenda: Eight
Ways to End
Poverty Now. Global
Justice.
Theory
Practice
Rhetoric
7: 3–11.
Consulted
websites
Pogge’s
personal web
page:
http://pantheon.yale.edu/~tp4/index.html.
Information
from the
Brazilian
government
about the
Bolsa Família
programme,
March 2013:
http://www2.planalto.gov.br/especiais
/caderno-destaques/marco-2013/gestao-em-destaque/erradicacao-
da-extrema-pobreza.
World Bank
evaluation of
the Bolsa
Família
programme,
2013:
http://go.worldbank.org/3QI1C7B5U0.
Pogge’s
lecture at the
International
Conference on
Realizing
Global
Justice:
Theory and
Practice:
http://mediasite.uit.no/Mediasite/Catalog
/Full/11629ab59d35420d8ab
50d3ae1263be621.
Measuring
Poverty and
Gender
Disparities:
http://www.genderpoverty
measure.org
Information
about the
health impact
fund at
www.healthimpactfund.org.
Global Gender
Gap Report
2013 at:
http://www3.weforum.org
/docs/WEF_GenderGap_Report_2013.pdf.
Boston
Consulting
Group, “Global
Wealth 2013:
Maintaining
Momentum in a
Complex
World,” 4 and
11, available
at
www.bcg.de/documents
/file135355.pdf.